≡ Menu

A Note: Graves, Sweeney and Goldmarkbilanz — Whither Sweeney and Schmidt’s Tageswertbilanz

Graeme Dean UNIVERSITY OF SYDNEY
and
Frank L. Clarke UNIVERSITY OF NEWCASTLE

A NOTE: GRAVES, SWEENEY AND GOLDMARKBILANZ — WHITHER SWEENEY AND SCHMIDT’S TAGESWERTBILANZ?

Abstract: Graves’ [1987] very competent and welldocumented descriptions of Mahlberg’s and Schmalenbach’s Goldmarkbilanz techniques should raise no objections on technical grounds. He ably captures and amplifies the mechanical aspects of these major Betriebswirtschaftslehre proposals. However, the linking of Sweeney with these Goldmarkbilanz proposals in the title and in the first few and then in the final pages of the article, is cause for concern. By only considering links with the Goldmarkbilanz techniques, Graves does less than reasonable justice to Sweeney’s development of the case for Stabilized Accounting. By not considering the other major stabilization proponent, Fritz Schmidt, albeit a proponent of re¬placement cost based stabilization, Graves provides only a partial explanation of the myriad of factors influencing the development of Sweeney’s inflation accounting proposals.

Graves’ [1987] very competent descriptions of Mahlberg’s and Schmalenbach’s Goldmarkbilanz (Gold mark balance sheet accounting) techniques should raise no objections on technical grounds. He ably captures and amplifies the mechanical aspects of these major Betriebswirtschaftslehre (academic discipline relating to theory of the firm) stabilization proposals. But, in telling only part of the story, he may do less than reasonable justice to Henry Sweeney’s development of the case for Stabilized Accounting. Graves acknowledges that Schmidt [1921] contains the first comprehensive statement in the accounting literature of current value (cost) accounting. But then, (in foot¬note 2) explains “[as Schmidt’s organic stabilization theory was] distinct from the goldmark model. . . [it] is not discussed in this study.” This exclusion results in a partial presentation of the links between Henry Sweeney’s ideas on inflation accounting and those already well developed by European business econo¬mists, resulting, inter alia, in the German gold mark model.

Importantly, telling only part of the story when coupled with the tendency for “earlier accounting knowledge to become lost to future accounting scholars” [Bricker, 1988], creates the po¬tential for readers to misinterpret the relative impacts of the ideas of Mahlberg, Schmalenbach and those of Schmidt, on Sweeney. Even worse, younger academics may perceive Sweeney to have been an indexed or constant purchasing power advocate, a proposition that Clarke [1976 and 1982] and Tweedie and Whittington [1984], inter alia, have refuted.

It is reasonable also to argue that Graves’ account of the Mahlberg and Schmalenbach proposals sheds little further light on either the connections between German Betriebswirtschaftslehre theories and Sweeney on the one hand; and the substantial thrust and essence of Sweeney’s proposals, on the other. The examinations, of the latter by Clarke [1976 and 1982] and the former by Clarke and Dean [1986 and 1988],1 provide the basis of this note.

From a historiographical perspective these facets of Graves’ contribution arise form the manner in which he draws on “Sweeney 1927” and “Sweeney 1928” and then moves directly to “Sweeney 1936.” Sweeney’s articles, of which there were thirteen between 1928 and 1936, are not canvassed; an omission aggravated by Graves not attributing any significance to the pause in Sweeney’s writings from February 1928 to December 1930. Yet both the pause and the developments underlying those other articles were essential elements of Sweeney’s process of sortingout his ideas between the completion of the first draft of his Ph.D. thesis in May 1927 and the 1936 publication of his stabilization techniques — an edited version of his completed Ph.D. manuscript. We argue, however, that a different and broader perception of the circumstances affecting Sweeney’s proposal, can be entertained. This note develops that broader perception. In particular, it draws upon the strong evidence of Fritz Schmidt’s ideas underlying the development of Sweeney’s stabilization thesis.

Accordingly, consider first Schmidt’s prominence in the Betriebswirtschaftslehre movement in general, and in the development of Tageswertbilanz proposals in particular. Then, consider the unequivocal links between Sweeney’s preference for stabilization based on replacement prices or reproductive costs and the impact of Schmidt’s Tageswertbilanz on the development of Sweeney’s stabilization ideas.

SCHMIDT, BETRIEBSWIRTSCHAFTSLEHRE AND TAGESWERTE

Elsewhere, Schmidt’s “organic” Betriebswirtschaft theory (theory of the firm) has been described in detail [Clarke and Dean, 1986]. Schmidt argued for Tageswertbilanz, i.e., a system of accounting using replacement cost valuations at the sales date (for factor inputs of items sold) and replacement costs as at balance sheet date for unsold items. His method aimed to ensure a relative maintenance of value — Das Prinzip der relativen Werterhaltung — ensuring thereby that the firm’s capital was retained in the same proportion to the total capital in the economy, as it bore at the date of the transaction giving rise to the original transaction data.2 He perceived accounting as an integral part of the process of efficiently allocating resources in the economy. In our 1986 article we noted that he “proposed his organic current value accounting in a deliberate attempt to place the theory of the firm, and accounting for the firm, in the context of a dynamic economy” (p. 69). Schmidt’s concept of the maintained firm entailed the retention of:

(i) its relative physical capacity to satisfy consumers’ needs,
(ii) its relative share of the market for its production, and
(iii) its relative overall share in the production fabric of the economy.

The inappropriateness of this relativist organic concept in a dynamic market oriented system was discussed in detail in Clarke and Dean [1986].3
Notwithstanding this criticism, it is reasonable to think of Schmidt as a pathbreaker. Seicht [1982] and Schneider [1981] suggest that Schmidt extended the earlier European works of Ciompa [1910], Kovero [1912] and Faes [1913] whilst translations we have commissioned of his work suggest he drew upon the ideas of the economist, Ricardo [1817] in formulating his system of Tageswertbilanz. In the AngloAmerican literature Mattessich [1982] suggests Schmidt [1921] provided the first comprehensive current cost accounting system — Graves con2Discussion of Schmidt’s relative maintenance of value principle appears in Clarke and Dean [1986, pp. 6970 and 9899].

3It is ironic that Schmidt’s concern with an economy’s dynamics should result in a theory of accounting premised on firm continuity.

curs [1987, p. 35]. Another feature is that Schmidt’s influence spread beyond the domain of purely accounting matters. Schwantag [1951] explained that noted business cycles economist Gottfried Haberler was aware, and approved, of Schmidt’s 1927 monograph highlighting the connection be¬tween faulty accounting and the exacerbation of trade cycles. A similar line of argument was pursued by Mitchell [1923], Lacey [1952], Baxter [1955] and by many others (see Ray [1960] for details).

Schmidt, however, was not alone in 1920s Germany in pursuing a “dynamic” theory of business economics, in particular advocating a move from the “static” (balance sheet oriented) perspective to a more “dynamic” (income account oriented) perspective.4 Others to pursue the same theory in¬cluded Schmalenbach [1919], Geldmacher [1920], Mahlberg [1920], Prion [1921], Walb [1921], and Kalveram [1923; for more details see Clarke and Dean 1986, pp. 8388]. But, despite the prestige of those others, Schmidt was acknowledged as the intellectual leader of the “organic relativist” perspective, just described [Schranz, 1930, p. 166].

SWEENEY — PREFERENCE FOR “TAGESWERTE OR WIEDERBESCHAFFUNGSWERTE”

It is difficult to deduce from Graves’ account Sweeney’s overwhelming preference for asset valuations based on current/ replacement or reproductive costs — Tageswerte or Wiederbeschaffungswerte respectively. In this respect the account of “Infla¬tion Accounting and Henry Sweeney. . . ” is curiously skewed. For whereas Sweeney’s 1927 and 1928 articles might well be traced to the Goldmarkbilanz ideas of Mahlberg and Schmalen¬bach, over eighty percent of Stabilized Accounting [1936] uses the Tageswerte (current/replacement values) valuation of nonmonetary assets. We agree with Graves’ assessment that Schmalenbach [1921], and to a greater extent Mahlberg [1923], undoubtedly influenced Sweeney’s 1927 and 1928 works. But the extent of Sweeney’s recourse to Schmidt is unequivocal. In particular, the evidence presented in Clarke and Dean [1986 and 1988] suggests that Schmidt had at least as great an impact on Sweeney’s post 1928 works as did Mahlberg.

4″The ‘statists’ objective [is to produce a] realistic snapshot of the entity’s current assets, liabilities and net worth . . . [whilst] the ‘dynamists’ objective [aims at] measuring accurately the performance of an entity resulting from the transactions for the period” [Tweedie and Whittington, 1984, p. 21].
5For a discussion of Mahlberg’s impact on Sweeney see Graves [1989].

From January 1928 to December 1930 nothing was published in the accounting literature under Sweeney’s name. Possibly this was a period in which he reflected on criticism of his earlier works. In several of his post 1928 works reference is made to one such critic, Fritz Schmidt [1930, pp. 280 and 284; 1931, pp. 166 and 17677; 1933, p. 190; 1935, p. 199 and 1936, pp. 4042, 47 and 193]. In the 1936 preface of Stabilized Accounting (p. xiv) he declared he became fully aware of Schmidt and his ideas in 1929, through Schmidt’s criticism of his “concepts of the fundamentals of stabilized accounting.” Later in the text (p. 40) Sweeney refers to Schmidt as “the German authority on stabilized accounting.” Although not specifically stated in any of Sweeney’s works it appears likely these deliberations oc¬curred after Schmidt delivered a paper on Valuation at the 1929 International Accounting Congress held in New York in Sep¬tember. Indirect support for this emerges in Sweeney [1935, p. 191]. In the preface of Stabilized Accounting Sweeney suggests the pause in his writings was to take account of “the French literature . . . which had benefited from the earlier experiments in neighbouring Germany . . . [which were based on replace¬ment cost ideas of the Germans] and [thus] tended to be more mature, concrete and practical” (p. xxii). These points link Sweeney’s ideas, and certainly his preferred mode of stabilized accounting, more with Schmidt than with any of the other Betriebswirtschaftslehre theorists.

As noted Sweeney’s preference for replacement or reproduc¬tive cost has been identified elsewhere [Clarke, 1976 and 1982, Mattessich, 1982, Tweedie and Whittington, 1984 and Clarke and Dean 1986 and 1988]. But it might be useful to reflect on the significance of that preference for every analysis of Sweeney’s adoption of the German indexation methods as part of Stabilized Accounting.

It seems that in many parts of the accounting literature Sweeney’s use of indexation or scaling techniques has been taken to be evidence of his affinity with scaling accounts data per se, rather than as a means of his primary end — achieving homogeneity in accounting data. Pursuit of this was stated in his 1935 article “to make accounting data more accurate by re¬moving much of the effect of the fluctuations in the value of money” [1935, p. 185]. In the professional literature promoting various forms of indexed (general price level or constant dollar) methods, attributing unwarranted importance to the scaling might be expected. The emphasis there, rightly or unequivo¬cally, is on the techniques. But, drawing such inferences from part of the historical analysis of the development of ideas is less than conducive to the production of a penetrating history.

Evidence that Sweeney opted for the convenience of indexa¬tion of historical cost data, rather than a “pure” replacement method per se, is to be found in several sources. First, with respect to its arithmetical simplicity, his approbation is reason¬ably evidenced in the 1927 and 1928 articles (to which Graves refers). It continues through both “Income” [1933] and “Capi¬tal” [1933] as well as “How Inflation Affects Balance Sheets” [1934]. It is explicit in “Stabilized Appreciation” [1932, p. 115]; in “The Technique of Stabilizing Accounting” [1935, p. 197]; and reiterated in Stabilized Accounting [1936, pp. 7, 42, 51, 159, et al.]. “The Technique of Stabilized Accounting” [1935], for example, alludes to his ranking of priorities — homogeneity first and replacement or reproduction costs second — explaining:

. . . valuation at cost of reproduction . . . conduces towards more homogeneous measurement of all assets than does valuation at original cost. (p. 197).
And in Stabilized Accounting [1936] he reinforces that thrust with the observation:
…stabilized accounting, although primarily interested in homogeneous measurement, cannot refrain from giving more approval to replacement cost as a valuation base than to ordinary original cost [em¬phasis added, p. 51].

Second, with respect to the arithmetical propriety of a scaling mechanism using index numbers, the thrust in 1927 and 1928 was toward arithmetical comparability [1927, p. 183 and 1928, p. 104]. Then in Stabilized Accounting, the contextual relations of Sweeney’s complaint of the mathematical impro¬priety of conventional accounting (p. 7) and the illustration of the basic indexation method (without any reference to infer¬ences to be drawn from the resulting data), are to be found. Unquestionably the emphasis was on the indexing method, more than on the substance of the data produced. And, thirdly, in the 1934 Harvard Business Review article on “Approximation of Appraisal Values by Index Numbers,” the linking of the scaling mechanism with approximation of replacement (or
6Sweeney suggests replacement cost valuation is to be preferred as it “seems capable of giving more useful information to all concerned” and it also yields “values that in the long run approximate more closely the values derived from the ideal method of determining value” [1936, p. 53].

Dean and Clarke: A Note: Graves, Sweeney and Goldmarkbilanz 107
reproductive cost) data, clearly emphasizes the tradeoff between simplicity of method and the substance of the resulting data.

POSTSCRIPT

Considering only the links with the Goldmarkbilanz propos¬als precludes identification of the extent of the influence the work of the leading replacement cost based stabilization theorist, Fritz Schmidt, had on the development of Sweeney’s Stabilized Accounting. Thus, it was argued that Graves [1987] provides only a partial explanation of the complex of the interacting factors influencing the development of Sweeney’s inflation accounting proposals.

Unravelling the myriad of influences on Sweeney’s work is a daunting task. Graves’ contribution has lightened the load for those who have been tracing through the European inflation accounting literature trying to identify the course of the development of ideas on how to make accounts incorporate the financial effects of price and price level changes. At this stage in that task it appears premature to interpret Sweeney’s resort to scaling methods as his entertaining a particulary strong affinity with the aims of either Mahlberg or Schmalenbach.

REFERENCES

Baxter, W., “The Accountant’s Contribution to the Trade Cycle.” Economica (May 1955), pp. 99112.
Bricker, R., “Knowledge Preservation in Accounting Research.” Abacus (September 1988), pp. 120131.
Ciompa, P., Grundriss einer Oekonometrie und die auf der Nationaloekonomie aufgebaute natuerliche Theorie der Buchhaltung Ein auf Grund neuer oekonometrischer Gleichungen erbrachter Beweis, das alle heutigen Bilanzen falsch dargestellt werden. [Outline of econometrics and the development of a natural theory of accounting based on economics. A proof that all present day balance sheets are stated incorrectly based on a new sketch of econometric equations.] Lemperg: C. E. Poeschel, 1910.
Clarke, F. L., “A Closer Look at Sweeney’s Stabilized Accounting Proposals.” Accounting and Business Research (Autumn 1976), pp. 264275.
, The Tangled Web of Price Variation Accounting. New York: Gar¬
land, 1982.
Clark, F. L. and G. W. Dean, “Schmidt’s Betriebswirtschaft Theory.” Abacus (September 1986), pp. 65102.
, “European Influences in the Seduction of Henry Sweeney.” Paper
presented at the 11th Congress of the European Accounting Association, Nice 1988.
Faes, E., Die Beruecksichtigung der Wertverminderung des stehenden Kapitals in den Jahresbilanzen der Erwerbswirtschaften. [Consideration of declining capital values in annual balance sheets of companies.] Tuebingen: Privately published, 1913.
Geldmacher, E., “Bilanzsorgen.” [Balance sheet worries.] Industrie und Handels
zeitung (1920), pp. 364, 378, 385, 392, 398 & 406. Graves, O. F., “Accounting for Inflation: Henry Sweeney and the German
GoldMark Model.” The Accounting Historians Journal, (Spring 1987), pp.
3355.
, “Mahlberg’s Valuation Theory.” Abacus (March 1989), pp. 2230.
Kalveram, W., Die kaufmaennische Rechnungsfuehrung unter dem Einfluss der
Geldentwertung. [Commercial accounting under the influence of changes in
the value of money.] Berlin: Spaeth und Linde, 1923. Kovero, I., Die Bewertung der Vermoegensgegenstaende in den Jahresbilanzen der
privaten Untemehmungen mit besonderer Beruecksichtigung der nicht
realisierten Verluste und Gewinne. [Revaluation of fixed assets in annual
balance sheets of private companies with special regard to unrealized
profits and losses.] Berlin: Privately published, 1912. Lacey, K., Profit Measurement and Price Changes. Bath: Pitman, 1952. Mahlberg, W., “Wirtschaftsrelativitaet.” [Economic relativities.] Zeitschrift fuer
Handelswissenschaft und Handelspraxis (1920: Heft 6, 8 & 9) pp. 133136,
1826 & 1957. __, Bilanztechnik und Bewertung bei schwankender Waehrung. [Balance
sheet technique and valuation during periods of currency fluctuation.]
Leipzig: G. A. Gloeckner, 1921; 2d ed. 1922; 3d ed. 1923. Mattessich, R., “On the Evolution of Inflation Accounting.” Economia Aziendale
(Vol. 1, No. 3 1982), pp. 349381. Mitchell, W. C, “Accountants and Economics with Reference to the Business
Cycle.” The Journal of Accountancy (March 1923), pp. 161171. Prion, W., Die Finanzierung und Bilanz wirtschaftlicher Betriebe unter dem
Einfluss der Geldentwertung. [Financing and balance sheet presentation of
business operations under the influence of inflation.]Berlin: Julius Springer,
1921. Ray, D. D., Accounting and Business Fluctuations. Gainesville: University of
Florida Press, 1960. Ricardo, D., The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. New York:
Macmillan, 1817.
Schmalenbach, E., “Grundlagen dynamischer Bilanzlehre.” [Dynamic ac¬counting.] Zeitschrift fuer handelswissenschaftliche Forschung (1919), pp.
160 & 65101.
, “Geldwertausgleich in der bilanzmaessigen Erfolgsrechnung.”
[Currency stabilization in the balance sheet approach to income determina¬tion.] Zeitschrift fuer handelswissenschaftliche Forschung (October 1921), pp.
40117. Schmidt, F., Die organische Bilanz in Rahmen der Wirtschaft. [The organic
balance sheet in the framework of the economy.] Leipzig: G. A. Gloeckner,
1921; 2d ed., Die organische Tageswertbilanz. [Organic current value balance
sheet.] 1922; & 3d ed., 1929.
, “Die Industriekonjunktur — Ein Rechenfehler!.” [Business cycles
— an accounting error!] Zeitschrift fuer Betriebswirtschaft, (Vol. 4 1927), pp.
129; 87114 & 164199. Schneider, von D., Geschichte Betriebswirtschaftlicher Theorie. [History of the
theory of business economics.] Muenchen/Wien: R. Oldenbourg, 1981. Schranz, A., “Modem German Accountancy.” The Accounting Review, (June
1930), pp. 16267. Schwantag, K., “F. Schmidt’s wissenschaftliches Werk.” [F. Schmidt’s academic
work.] Zeitschrift fuer Betriebswirtschaft, (January 1951), pp. 114.

Dean and Clarke: A Note: Graves, Sweeney and Goldmarkbilanz 109
Siecht, G., Bilanztheorien. [Accounting theories.] Wien: Physica, 1982. Sweeney, H. W., “Effects of Inflation on German Accounting.” The Journal of
Accountancy, (March 1927), pp. 178191.
, “German Inflation Accounting.” The Journal of Accountancy,
(February 1928), pp. 104116.
, “The Maintenance of Capital.” The Accounting Review, (December
1930), pp. 277287.
, “Stabilized Depreciation.” The Accounting Review, (September
1931), pp. 165178. _, “Capita1.” The Accounting Review, (September 1933), pp. 185199.
, “Income.” The Accounting Review, (December 1933), pp. 323335.
, “The Technique of Stabilized Accounting.” The Accounting Re
view, (June 1935), pp. 185205.
, Stabilized Accounting. New York: Harper and Brothers 1936;
reproduced by Arno Press 1976; reprint, Holt, Rinehart and Winston 1964. Tweedie, D. and G. Whittington, The Debate on Inflation Accounting. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1984. Walb, E., Das Problem der Scheingewinne. [The problem of fictitious profits.]
Freiburg in Brisgau: Walter Momber, 1921.